Homicide rates and housing prices in Cali and Bogotá, D. C.
Tasas de homicidio y precios de la vivienda en Cali y Bogotá, D. C.
Taxas de homicídio e preços de habitação em Cali e Bogotá, D. C.
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.15446/cuad.econ.v40n83.82495Palabras clave:
Urban economics, urban crime, housing prices (en)economia urbana, crime urbano, preços da habitação (pt)
economía urbana, crimen urbano, precios de viviendas (es)
Descargas
Currently, the list of most violent cities in the world is dominated by Latin American cities. In 2015, Cali registered 65 homicides per 100,000 inhabitants. In Bogotá, the rate was 17 per 100,000 inhabitants. However, crime is not homogeneously distributed within the urban area, and literature indicates that the local response to crime affects the housing market. The objective of this paper is to estimate the relationship between housing prices and homicide rates in two Colombian cities: Cali and Bogotá. With the use of diverse sources of information and different econometric methodologies, we found that a 10% increase in homicide rates provokes a 2% decrease in housing prices in Cali and 1.8% in Bogotá.
Actualmente, las ciudades más violentas del mundo se encuentran en Latinoamérica. En 2015, Cali registró 65 homicidios por cada 100 000 habitantes. Para ese mismo año, en Bogotá, la tasa de homicidios reportada fue 17 por cada 100 000 habitantes. Dado que la criminalidad se distribuye heterogéneamente dentro de las ciudades, la literatura señala que la respuesta de las personas ante la criminalidad afecta el mercado inmobiliario. El objetivo de este artículo es estimar la relación entre los precios de la vivienda y las tasas de homicidios en dos ciudades colombianas: Cali y Bogotá. Usando diversas fuentes de información y diferentes métodos cuantitativos de estimación, el principal resultado encontrado fue que ante un incremento del 10 % en las tasas de homicidio, hay una disminución del 2 % en los precios de vivienda en Cali y de 1,8 % en Bogotá, D. C.
Atualmente, as cidades mais violentas do mundo estão na América Latina. Em 2015, Cali registrou 65 homicídios por cada 100.000 habitantes. Nesse mesmo ano, em Bogotá, a taxa de homicídio registrada foi de 17 por cada 100.000 habitantes. Dado que a criminalidade está distribuída de forma heterogênea nas cidades, a literatura indica que a resposta das pessoas ao crime afeta o mercado imobiliário. O objetivo deste artigo é estimar a relação entre os preços da habitação e as taxas de homicídio em duas cidades colombianas: Cali e Bogotá. Usando várias fontes de informação e diferentes métodos de estimativa quantitativa, o principal resultado encontrado foi que, diante de um aumento de 10% nas taxas de homicídio, há uma queda de 2% nos preços da habitação em Cali e uma queda de 1,8% em Bogotá DC.
Referencias
Atkinson, G., Healey, A., & Mourato, S. (2005). Valuing the cost of violent crime: A stated preference approach. Oxford Economic Papers, 57(4), 559-585.
Besley, T., & Mueller, H. (2012). Estimating the peace dividend: The impact of violence on housing prices in Northern Ireland. American Economic Review, 102(2), 810-813.
Bowes, D., & Ihlanfeldt, K. (2001). Identifying the impacts of rail transit stations on residential property values. Journal of Urban Economics, 50(1), 1-25.
Buonanno, P., Montolio, D., & Raya-Vílchez, J. (2013). Housing prices and crime perception. Empirical Economics, 45(1), 305-321.
Brueckner, J. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. The MIT Press.
Cameron, C., & Miller, D. (2015). A practitioner’s guide to cluster-robust inference. The Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), 317-372.
Carson, R., Flores, N., & Meade, N. (2001). Contingent valuation: Controversies and evidence. Environmental and Resource Economics, 19(2), 173-210.
Ceccato, V., & Wilhelmsson, M. (2011). The impact of crime on apartment prices: Evidence from Stockholm, Sweden. Geografiska Annaler: Series B, Swedish Society for Antropology and Geography, 81-103.
Combes, P., Duranton, P., Gobillon, L., & Roux, S. (2010). Estimating agglomeration effects with history, geology and worker fixed effects. In E. Glaeser (Ed.) Agglomeration economies. Chicago IL: University of Chicago Press.
Combes, P., & Gobillon, L. (2015). The empirics of agglomeration economies. In G. Duranton, V. Henderson & W. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics (Vol. 5, 247-348). Elsevier.
Consejo Ciudadano para la Seguridad Pública y la Justicia Penal – CCSPJP (2016). Caracas, Venezuela, the Most Violent City in the World. En Seguridad Justicia y Paz. http://www.seguridadjusticiaypaz.org.mx/biblioteca/download/6-prensa/231-caracas-venezuela-the-most-violentcity-in-the-world
Cohen, M., Rust. R., Steen, S., & Tidd, S. (2004). Willingness-to-Pay for crime control programs. Criminology, 42(1), 89-109.
DANE. (2017). Encuesta Multipropósito 2017. Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística, República de Colombia.
Departamento Administrativo de Hacienda Municipal (2012). El catastro en Cali: Evolución y recomendaciones de política. Alcaldía de Santiago de Cali.
Di Tella, R., Edwards, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2010). Introduction to “The economics of crime: Lessons for and from Latin America.” In R. Di Tella, S. Edwards, & E. Schargrodsky (Eds.), The Economics of Crime: Lessons for and from Latin America (pp. 1–15). National Bureau of Economic Research. University of Chicago Press.
Fallis, G. (1985). Housing economics. Butterworths.
Frischtak, C., & Mandel, B. (2012). Crime, house price, and inequality: The effect of UPPs in Rio. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No. 542.
Fujita, M., & Thisse, J. F. (2013). Economics of agglomeration: Cities, industrial location and globalization (2 ed.). Cambridge University Press.
Gaviria, A., & Vélez, C. (2002). Who bears the burden of crime and violence in Colombia? In Colombia poverty report (Vol. 2, pp. 146-161). World Bank.
Gibbons, S. (2004). The cost of urban property crime. The Economic Journal, 114(499), 441-463.
Glaeser, E., & Sacerdote, B. (1999). Why is there more Crime in Cities? Journal of Political Economy, 107(S6), S225-S258.
Hellman, D., & Naroff, J. (1979). the impact of crime on urban residential property values. Urban Studies, 16(1), 105-112.
Houser, T., Hsiang, S., Kopp, R., & Larsen, K. (2015). Economic risk of climate change: An American prospectus. Columbia University Press.
INML. (2015). Comportamiento del homicidio. Colombia 2015. Instituto Nacional de Medicina Legal y Ciencias Forences. República de Colombia.
Koster, H., & Rouwendal, J. (2013). Agglomeration, commuting costs, and the internal structure of cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 43(2), 352-366.
Levitt, S., & List, J. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2), 153-174.
Lynch, A. & Rasmussen, D. (2001). Measuring the impact of crime on house prices. Applied Economics, 33(15), 1981-1989.
Lucas, R., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2002). On the internal structure of cities. Econometrica, 70(4) 1445-1476.
O’Flaherty, B., & Sethi, R. (2015). Urban Crime. In G. Duranton, J. V. Henderson & W. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics (1st. ed., Vol. 5A, pp. 1519-1621). Elsevier.
Ridker, R., & Henning, J. A. (1967). The determinants of residential property values with special reference to air pollution. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 49(2), 246-257.
Rizzo, M. (1979). The effect of crime on residential rents and property values. The American Economist, 23(1), 16-21.
Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82(1), 34-55.
Rosenthal, S., & Strange, W. (2008), The attenuation of human capital spillovers, Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), 373-389.
Semana (2019, May 4). Aumenta el número de policías para Bogotá, ¿es suficiente? Revista Semana. https://www.semana.com/nacion/articulo/aumento-del-pie-de-fuerza-y-parque-automotor-para-bogota/608245.
Shapiro, R. & Hassett, K. (2012). The economic benefits of reducing violent crime: A case study of 8 American cities. Center for American Progress, June 2012.
Soares, R. (2006). the welfare cost of violence across countries. Journal of Health Economics, 25(5), 821-846.
Soares, R. (2010). Welfare costs of crime and common violence: A critical review (Working Paper, 581). Departamento de Economía, Pontifical Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro and IZA.
Thaler, R. (1978). a note on the value of crime control: Evidence from the property market. Journal of Urban Economics, 5(1), 137-145.
The Economist. (2016, February 3). The world’s most violent cities. http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2016/02/daily-chart-3
Tita, G., Petras, T., & Greenbaum, R. (2006). Crime and residential choice: A neighbourhood level analysis of the impact of crime on housing prices. Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 22(4), 299-317.
White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817-838.
Cómo citar
APA
ACM
ACS
ABNT
Chicago
Harvard
IEEE
MLA
Turabian
Vancouver
Descargar cita
Licencia
Derechos de autor 2021 Cuadernos de EconomíaCuadernos de Economía a través de la División de Bibliotecas de la Universidad Nacional de Colombia promueve y garantiza el acceso abierto de todos sus contenidos. Los artículos publicados por la revista se encuentran disponibles globalmente con acceso abierto y licenciados bajo los términos de Creative Commons Atribución-No_Comercial-Sin_Derivadas 4.0 Internacional (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), lo que implica lo siguiente: